Short-rate model

In the context of interest rate derivatives, a short-rate model is a mathematical model that describes the future evolution of interest rates by describing the future evolution of the short rate, usually written r_t \,.

Contents

The short rate

The short rate, r_t \,, is the (annualized) interest rate at which an entity can borrow money for an infinitesimally short period of time from time t. Specifying the current short rate does not specify the entire yield curve. However no-arbitrage arguments show that, under some fairly relaxed technical conditions, if we model the evolution of r_t \, as a stochastic process under a risk-neutral measure Q then the price at time t of a zero-coupon bond maturing at time T is given by

 P(t,T) = \mathbb{E}\left[\left. \exp{\left(-\int_t^T r_s\, ds\right) } \right| \mathcal{F}_t \right]

where \mathcal{F} is the natural filtration for the process. Thus specifying a model for the short rate specifies future bond prices. This means that instantaneous forward rates are also specified by the usual formula

 f(t,T) = - \frac{\partial}{\partial T} \ln(P(t,T)).

Particular short-rate models

Throughout this section W_t\, represents a standard Brownian motion under a risk-neutral probability measure and dW_t\, its differential. Other than Rendleman–Bartter and Ho–Lee, which do not capture the mean reversion of interest rates, these models can be thought of as specific cases of Ornstein–Uhlenbeck processes. Where the model is lognormal, a variable X_t \,, is assumed to follow an Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process and r_t \, is assumed to follow r_t = \exp{X_t}\,. Ho-Lee and subsequent models can be calibrated to market data, meaning that these can exactly return the price of bonds comprising the yield curve.

  1. Merton's Model (1973) [1] models the short rate as dr_t = r_{0}%2Bat%2B\sigma W^{*}_{t}: where W^{*}_{t} is a one-dimensional Brownian motion under the spot martingale measure.
  2. The Vasicek model (1977) [2] models the short rate as dr_t = a(b-r_t)\, dt %2B \sigma \, dW_t
  3. The Rendleman–Bartter model (1980) [3] models the short rate as dr_t = \theta r_t\, dt %2B \sigma r_t\, dW_t
  4. The Cox–Ingersoll–Ross model (1985) [4] supposes dr_t = (\theta_t-\alpha r_t)\,dt %2B \sqrt{r_t}\,\sigma_t\, dW_t
  5. The Ho–Lee model (1986) [5] models the short rate as dr_t = \theta_t\, dt %2B \sigma\, dW_t
  6. The Hull–White model (1990) [6] - also called the extended Vasicek model - posits dr_t = (\theta_t-\alpha r_t)\,dt %2B \sigma_t \, dW_t. In many presentations one or more of the parameters \theta, \alpha and \sigma are not time-dependent. The model may also be applied as lognormal.
  7. The Black–Derman–Toy model (1990) [7] has  d\ln(r) = [\theta_t %2B \frac{\sigma '_t}{\sigma_t}\ln(r)]dt %2B \sigma_t\, dW_t for time-dependent short rate volatility and d\ln(r) = \theta_t\, dt %2B \sigma \, dW_t otherwise; the model is lognormal.
  8. The Black–Karasinski model (1991), [8] which is lognormal, has  d\ln(r) = [\theta_t-\phi_t \ln(r)] \, dt %2B \sigma_t\, dW_t ; the model may be seen as the lognormal application of Hull-White.[1]
  9. The Kalotay–Williams–Fabozzi model (1993) [9] has the short rate as  d \ln(r_t) = \theta_t\, dt %2B \sigma\, dW_t, a lognormal analogue to the Ho–Lee model, and a special case of the Black–Derman–Toy model.

Multi-factor short-rate models

Besides the above one-factor models, there are also multi-factor models of the short rate, among them the best known are the Longstaff and Schwartz two factor model and the Chen three factor model (also called "stochastic mean and stochastic volatility model"):

  1. The Longstaff–Schwartz model (1992) [10] supposes the short rate dynamics are given by:  dX_t = (a_t-b X_t)\,dt %2B \sqrt{X_t}\,c_t\, dW_{1t}, d Y_t = (d_t-e Y_t)\,dt %2B \sqrt{Y_t}\,f_t\, dW_{2t}, where the short rate is defined as  dr_t = (\mu X %2B \theta Y)dt %2B \sigma_t \sqrt{Y} dW_{3t} .
  2. The Chen model (1996) [11] which has a stochastic mean and volatility of the short rate, is given by :  dr_t = (\theta_t-\alpha_t)\,dt %2B \sqrt{r_t}\,\sigma_t\, dW_t, 
d \alpha_t = (\zeta_t-\alpha_t)\,dt %2B \sqrt{\alpha_t}\,\sigma_t\, dW_t,  
d \sigma_t = (\beta_t-\sigma_t)\,dt %2B \sqrt{\sigma_t}\,\eta_t\, dW_t.

Other interest rate models

The other major framework for interest rate modelling is the Heath–Jarrow–Morton framework (HJM). Unlike the short rate models described above, this class of models is generally non-Markovian. This makes general HJM models computationally intractable for most purposes. The great advantage of HJM models is that they give an analytical description of the entire yield curve, rather than just the short rate. For some purposes (e.g., valuation of mortgage backed securities), this can be a big simplification. The Cox–Ingersoll–Ross and Hull–White models in one or more dimensions can both be straightforwardly expressed in the HJM framework. Other short rate models do not have any simple dual HJM representation.

The HJM framework with multiple sources of randomness, including as it does the Brace–Gatarek–Musiela model and market models, is often preferred for models of higher dimension.

References

  1. ^ Merton, Robert C. (1973). "Theory of Rational Option Pricing". Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4 (1): 141–183. http://www.jstor.org/pss/3003143. 
  2. ^ Vasicek, Oldrich (1977). "An Equilibrium Characterisation of the Term Structure". Journal of Financial Economics 5 (2): 177–188. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(77)90016-2. 
  3. ^ Rendleman, R. and B. Bartter (1980). "The Pricing of Options on Debt Securities". Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 15: 11–24. doi:10.2307/2979016. 
  4. ^ Cox, J.C., J.E. Ingersoll and S.A. Ross (1985). "A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates". Econometrica 53: 385–407. doi:10.2307/1911242. 
  5. ^ T.S.Y. Ho and S.B. Lee (1986). "Term structure movements and pricing interest rate contingent claims". Journal of Finance 41. doi:10.2307/2328161. 
  6. ^ John Hull and Alan White (1990). "Pricing interest-rate derivative securities". The Review of Financial Studies 3 (4): 573–592. http://www.defaultrisk.com/pa_related_24.htm. 
  7. ^ Black, F.; Derman, E. and Toy, W. (1990). "A One-Factor Model of Interest Rates and Its Application to Treasury Bond Options". Financial Analysts Journal: 24–32. http://savage.wharton.upenn.edu/FNCE-934/syllabus/papers/Black_Derman_Toy_FAJ_90.pdf. 
  8. ^ Black, F.; Karasinski, P. (1991). "Bond and Option pricing when Short rates are Lognormal". Financial Analysts Journal: 52–59. http://www.defaultrisk.com/pa_related_29.htm. 
  9. ^ Kalotay, Andrew J.; Williams, George O.; Fabozzi, Frank J. (1993). "A Model for Valuing Bonds and Embedded Options". Financial Analysts Journal (CFA Institute Publications) 49 (3): 35–46. doi:10.2469/faj.v49.n3.35. http://www.cfapubs.org/doi/abs/10.2469/faj.v49.n3.35. 
  10. ^ Longstaff, F.A. and Schwartz, E.S. (1992). "Interest Rate Volatility and the Term Structure: A Two-Factor General Equilibrium Model". Journal of Finance 47 (4): 1259–82. http://efinance.org.cn/cn/FEshuo/19920901Interest%20Rate%20Volatility%20and%20the%20Term%20Structure%20A%20Two-Factor%20General%20Equilibrium%20Model,%20pp.%201259-1282.pdf. 
  11. ^ Lin Chen (1996). "Stochastic Mean and Stochastic Volatility — A Three-Factor Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates and Its Application to the Pricing of Interest Rate Derivatives". Financial Markets, Institutions, and Instruments 5: 1–88. 

Bibliography